Free Trade vs. Production Integration

AuthorAnthony J. Payne
ProfessionProfessor of Politics, University of Sheffield, UK. He is the author of several books on Caribbean politics and international relations
Pages34-66
34 | The Political History of CARICOM
Not until the second half of the 1960s did advocates of a West
Indian economic community turn their attention to the more serious
business of regional economic integration. The immediate cause of this
development was the publication in 1965 of an important new analysis
of the economic underdevelopment of the Commonwealth Caribbean.
The work was entitled The Economics of Development in Small Countries
with Special Reference to the Caribbean and its author was William
Demas.1 Demas is one of the central figures of our story. In 1965 he was
the Head of the Economic Planning Division of the Trinidad government
and thus a senior civil servant, but for five months from January to June
1964 he had been a guest fellow of the Centre for Developing Area
Studies at McGill University in Montreal. The outcome of this sabbatical
was the appearance of the slim, but influential, study of the West Indian
economy which we have just mentioned.
The book’s significance derived from the fact that Demas realised
earlier than most that the post-war pattern of economic growth in the
West Indies — for which so many extravagant claims had been made
by the various governments concerned — had not been accompanied
by any genuine development of the regional economy and was indeed
beset by a number of fundamental weaknesses. In the passage of time
these shortcomings can be seen to be many, but by 1965 two already
stood out.2 Firstly, the level of unemployment and underemployment
in the region was still high and, so far from decreasing over the previous
decade, was thought actually to have grown — and not only in absolute
numbers but also as a percentage of total population. The high wage
CHAPTER two
Free Trade vs.
Production Integration
Free Trade vs. Production Integration | 35
rates paid in the new mineral and manufacturing sectors had the perverse
effect of raising the reserve price of labour and thus of encouraging
people to sacrifice low-paid agricultural employment in order to join
the ranks of the urban unemployed. At the same time, most of the
imported technology used in these sectors was highly capital-intensive
and unsuited to the special needs of the labour surplus economies into
which it had been introduced. For example, the 146 industries which,
by the end of 1965, had been established in Jamaica under the incentive
legislation programme had provided a mere 9,000 jobs,3 whilst in
Trinidad the employment potential of industrialisation had been equally
disappointing: only 4,666 jobs were made available by ninety-nine new
industries between 1950 and 1963.4 Many more were needed, in view
of the steady year-by-year rise in the size of the total population of the
region,5 just to prevent the unemployment level from worsening.
Secondly, the use made of local West Indian resources in the process of
growth had been negligible. Foreign investors in the manufacturing
sector had preferred, on the whole, to locate within the Caribbean no
more of the production process than was necessary to be awarded the
tax incentives. The industries that grew up were usually, therefore, only
‘screwdriver’ final-assembly operations, producing shoes, cosmetics,
household chemicals, stoves, refrigerators and other similar consumer
goods. In the mineral sector, too, the value added locally to the region’s
major raw material exports was very small; for example, the bulk of the
bauxite mined in Jamaica and Guyana was shipped away in its original
form as an ore and its processing into alumina and aluminium — the
stages which contribute most to the final price — was undertaken outside
the region. Even the tourist industry was characterised by its failure to
create a web of linkages with local agriculture and was thus partly
responsible for the area’s growing imports of foodstuff.
Demas argued that the resulting failure of the West Indian states to
transform their economies during this period was no accident, but rather
that their capacity to achieve economic development was constrained
in a crucial manner by their small size, defined in terms of both land
area and population number.6 Here was the core of his analysis. The
smallness of the domestic market, he reasoned, imposed sharp limits on
36 | The Political History of CARICOM
the process of import-substitution industrialisation and thus removed
the option of balanced growth, incorporating a roughly equal mixture
of export stimulation and import substitution, a goal which could only
really be attained by large continental countries. In order to secure the
benefits of economies of scale, small economies had, therefore, of
necessity, to place special emphasis upon the production of a small
number of manufactures for export to world markets. The obstacles in
the way of capturing the necessary markets were, however, formidable:
the most prominent being restrictions against so-called ‘cheap
labour’ imports into the markets of the industrial countries; wage
rates in the under-developed countries which do not reflect the
true cost of labour as determined by relative factor supplies; the
low income-elasticity of demand in the advanced countries for
the simpler, labour-intensive products; the fear of creating excess
capacity in the face of the uncertainties of the world market; all
the numerous factors inhibiting incursions into export markets;
and, finally, the fact that nearly all underdeveloped countries are
protecting the simpler labour-intensive final consumer goods.7
In view of the difficulties thereby involved in the pursuit of both import
substitution and export stimulation, Demas turned his attention to two
alternative strategies. One was near or full economic integration with a
large country or large trading bloc on the lines of Puerto Rico’s relationship
with the United States or Luxembourg’s with the Benelux countries, but
that could be objected to on the grounds that it was a form of
‘neocolonialism’ unlikely to provide development in the smaller, poorer
partner of the alliance; the other was economic integration with
neighbouring underdeveloped countries. This was the direction, Demas
opined, ‘in which it appears more likely that many countries will move’,8
and which he was himself inclined to favour.
What in detail were the arguments which Demas marshalled behind
the case for regional economic integration? Let us start with a negative
point. They were not those of neo-classical customs union theory, for,
as he had already argued in an article on a West Indies customs union
written during the days of the Federation,9 the conventions of this theory

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT