Dutch Disease and Déjà Vu: Policy Advice for the T&T Economy in the Wake of a Second Oil Boom

AuthorBhoendradatt Tewari/Roger Hosein
Pages147-180
Chapter 6
Dutch Disease and Déjà Vu: Policy Advice
for the T&T Economy in the Wake of a
Second Oil Boom1
During the 1970s the Trinidad and Tobago (T&T) economy was blessed
by an oil boom occasioned by increases in both its production of crude
oil and the prices each barrel of crude oil fetched on the international
market. In the context of the Dutch Disease and the Resource Curse
thesis, a number of policies enacted by the government, at the time, were
erroneous. The T&T economy is once again faced with the prospects of
another boom in its hydrocarbon sector. This paper reviews the elements
of the Dutch Disease and Resource Curse thesis, which emerged in T&T
during the first oil boom and focuses on providing some policy advice to
the government of T&T the second time around.
This chapter was first published in the West Indian Journal of
Engineering, Vol. 26, No. 2, Jan 2004, pp. 1–21.
1 The authors acknowledge the invaluable comments of D. Mahabir, lecturer in the
Department of Economics, UWI
Trade, Investment & Development
148
6.1 INTRODUCTION
Since the 1970s the international trade literature has recognized the
structural effects and policy implications of a boom in a tradable
resource good. A boom in a primary export commodity can especially, in
terms of the empirical experience be either a boom or a curse. A resource
boom will benefit both national income and the balance of payments
whilst other sectors especially those in the non-booming tradable sector
can contract as their output levels and factor incomes fall.
Many researchers in the economics literature have emphasized natural
resource rents and their developmental potential. Natural resource
booms, however, although playing an important role in helping to
alleviate some of the traditional obstacles to development, including;
bridging fiscal deficits, savings and investment gaps and providing a
rapid inflow of foreign exchange, have also brought with it adverse side
effects.2 This paper reviews the impact of the first oil boom in T&T of
the 1970s and provides some policy advice for the government in the
context of a second oil boom which the country is expecting to engage
within a few years.
6.2 THE DUTCH DISEASE CONCEPT
The term ‘Dutch Disease’ which basically refers to the negative effects a
booming tradable resource has on other traditional export sectors, was
first used to refer to the experience of the Netherlands’ manufacturing
sector on account of the natural gas discoveries of the 1960s. In the
Dutch economy, the discovery of a massive pool of gas resources in the
Schlochteren area motivated a higher real exchange rate, triggered
principally by appreciating nominal wages in the Dutch economy,
especially in relation to Germany. The export boom caused an
appreciation of the Dutch currency (the guilder) significantly above
levels that attained prior to the discovery of natural gas, and in so doing
decreased the level of competitiveness of the Dutch industrial sector as
its real exchange rate appreciated. The exposition of the Dutch Disease in
what follows is based upon the works of Corden (1982) and Kamas
(1986).3
2 As early as 1776, Adam Smith argued that mining should not be high on the list of
choices of policy makers because it did not replace the capital, which was deployed in its
extraction (Smith, 1776, pg 562).
3 It should be noted that the Dutch Disease model has been deployed in the literature to
consistently deal with countries that have experienced energy sector booms. This model,
Dutch Disease 149
The Basic Model
Let us assume that we have two sectors, a traded sector (T) and a non-
traded sector (NT), Y is national income. The T sector has two main
components, booming (B) and non-booming (NB). Thus,
Y = T + NT
T = B + NB
If we assume that the non-traded goods sector has a positive income
elasticity of demand and the increase in income in the booming tradable
sector is of magnitude 'Y, of which D'Y is spent on the non-traded
sector (0<D<1), then a resource boom, by sprouting an increase in
demand for goods in the non-traded sector would also lead to an increase
in the price of goods in this same sector and hence, an increase in the
overall price level. The rise in the price level of goods in the non-traded
sector increases the profitability of this sector. This change occurs on
account of the spending effect (Se) of the boom (Corden, 1982).
The boom stimulates an expansion in the marginal product of factors of
production, which are employed in the booming sector, and this
encourages a flow of resources into this sector, this is the resource
movement effect (Re) of the resource boom. If we consider the Se and the
Re then the output of the non-booming traded goods sector will be lower
than it was initially, i.e. for the non-booming tradable sector, Re and Se
complement each other. Se expands the size of the non-traded sector
whilst Re contracts it, so that the eventual impact on the output of the
non-traded sector will depend on their relative magnitudes. However,
because the majority of commodities in the non-tradable sector are
services and given that in most developing economies services have an
income elasticity of demand which is positive, then one would expect
that with a resource boom the overall size of the non tradable sector
would expand.
The mechanics of the Se and Re movements can be explained in greater
detail as follows. With a resource boom (for example, a new oil
discovery) an increase in the country’s oil exports stimulates domestic
income. If all of the foreign currency earnings are spent on imports, then
there will be no impact on the domestic money supply, nor on the
however, is equally well applicable to any country which is experiencing a boom but in a
tradable goods sector for which domestic absorption is limited.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT